Unequal Distributions: Land Pressure in the World’s Least Densely-Population Country by Katie Niemeyer
In
1992, the Mongolian People’s Republic officially became recognized as simply “Mongolia”
after it adopted a democratic constitution, and, equally important, initiated a
dramatic shift from 70 years of socialism to a market economy. For the first time in over 2,200 years of
statehood, Mongolia established the institution of private land by allowing for
private property ownership by citizens with the exception of pastures and areas
designated for public use.[i] However, the significance of keeping about
82%[ii] of Mongolia’s land (an
area that is nearly twice the size of Texas in total) free and open to the
public while also trying to promote land privatization has caused significant
conflict, particularly in peri-urban areas.
My research of peri-urban livestock production near the capital city,
Ulaanbaatar, produced some interesting stories of this tension. These stories will take us on a journey
through two of the areas that I visited during my research: Bornuur County (soum) in Tov Province and Songinokhairkhan
District (düüreg) within the
municipality of Ulaanbaatar.
![]() |
Study area in
peri-urban Mongolia included Bornuur Soum, Bayanchandmani Soum, and
Songinokhairkhan District within the capital city, Ulaanbaatar.
|
Bornuur Soum, Tov
The soum of Bornuur is well known for its
agriculture – both crops and livestock.
In some areas, you are almost as likely to see a small planted field (by
U.S. standards) as you are a yurt (ger)
with a herd of sheep and goats. This is
relatively unique in Mongolia, as half of the 3 million people in the country
reside in the capital city, and around one third of the population depends on
extensive livestock husbandry for its livelihood.2 But in an
exciting trend for the development and diversification of Mongolia’s
agricultural sector, cultivation of field crops on privately-owned land also
gives rise to a new issue that Mongolia has not had to address before. Local officials in Bornuur have stated that
the most common complaint among their constituents involves free-roaming
livestock choosing the highly nutritious diet of the neighbor’s crops over the
degraded public rangeland full of noxious weeds.
According to a local official in Bornuur, “This is a problem not just in
our bag, but our soum. By last year’s census, our total amount of animals was
about 108,000 in this soum. Our soum’s total area is 114,000 ha. Our pasture
weight is overgrazed 4 times than normal. There has been a rift of dispute
cases between herders and crop farmers, as the enclosed fields of farmers get
trespassed by herders’ animals. Then farmers will confiscate the herders’
animals. These kinds of cases are common.”
When asked how local officials try to
solve these conflicts, she stated, “Our
policy from the soum is that herders herd their animals better and that farmers
fence their lands better. When there’s an inevitable dispute, we try to follow
mediation guidelines.” These
mediation guidelines, she went on to explain, involve an appraisal committee
that determines the amount of loss and necessary payment by the herder. If he or she decides not to reimburse the
farmer either with cash or livestock, then the case goes to court.
According to local officials, 40% of
Bornuur’s population live as semi-nomadic herders, and 120,000 animals survive
on 194,000 total hectares of land. This
leads to an overgrazing problem of 3-4 times the capacity of the public
pastureland. It’s not surprising that the
livestock, that have little knowledge or concern for fences, end up in the
fields of crop farmers.
Songinokhairkhan
District, Ulaanbaatar
During socialist times in Mongolia, the 21st
Subdistrict (khoroo) of
Songinokahirkhan was the largest agricultural unit providing milk to city. This trend continued during privatization in
the 1990s when Jargalant Village, one of the largest towns in the 21st
Khoroo, was established as the “agricultural development zone” for the city.[i]
As of last December, 2,200 households
owned over 16,900 head of livestock, most of which are raised on the public
pasture. The rangeland in this
administrative area is also in trouble due to heavy livestock densities – and
that was before a mistake within the different levels of government led to the
shrinking of public lands pasture for herders and their livestock.
In the 2003, Mongolia shifted its focus
from privatization of industry and commerce to the privatization of land for
every Mongolian citizen. A new law
passed the year before allowed each Mongolian citizen to claim a plot of land
of up to 0.07 hectares. The government
is still working on this process, distributing the land in a lottery-type fashion
year-by-year.
However, as with any massive state-level
transition, things do not always go as smoothly as hoped. One example has hit Songinokhairkhan
hard. According to a local official in the 21st Khoroo, “there has
been an egregious mistake in land allocation.” The Ulaanbaatar city council dedicated 1,400
hectares of land to private ownership in 21st Khoroo, an
administrative area that was supposed to be reserved strictly as an
agricultural zone. She stated
that now, 20,000 residents of the capital city are claiming their own slice of
paradise by “fencing their lands with
tires, iron bars, anything they can find.
Our land looks pristine, but it’s riddled with fenced areas […] They
notified neither us nor the district--decided it in the city-level […] This is
bound to create pasture scarcity, and we pleaded this on all levels [of
government].
![]() |
A typical view in villages outside of
Ulaanbaatar where people fence off their plots of land, called “hashas.” [Photo
Credit: Peter Bittner]
|
In economic development we often talk
about the importance of private land ownership and land tenure in promoting the
appropriate incentives to spur economic growth and prosperity. As a former student of economics, I agree
that this is an important institution that should be protected by the rule of
law. Now, as a student of agricultural
development, I see how the way in which an institutional change is implemented can be almost more important
than the policy shift itself. It is
critically important to consider how implementation actions influence all parties subject to the tangible
effects of policies such as privatization.
The injustice that the people, animals, and environment of the 21st
Khoroo will endure due to this decision and mismanagement has shown me that
when it comes to policy change, it’s the details that matter.
[1] Tumenbayar, Nyamaa. 2000. "Land Privatization
Optioin for Mongolia." Constituting the Commons: Crafting Sustainable
Commons in the New Millennium, the Eighth Biennial Conference of the
International Association for the Study of Common Property. Bloomington,
Indiana: Indiana University. http://dlc.dlib.indiana.edu/dlc/handle/10535/133.
[1] Fernandez-Gimenez, Maria E., Akira Kamimura, and
Batbuyan Batjav. 2008. Implementing Mongolia's Land Law: Progress and
Issues. Research Project, Nagoya University, Japan: Center for Asian Legal
Exchange.
[1] Interview with a 21st
Khoroo Local Official of Songinokhairkan District on July 20,2016.
Comments
Post a Comment